Difference between revisions of "Economics Lecture Five"

From Conservapedia
Jump to: navigation, search
m
(typo)
 
(77 intermediate revisions by 2 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
 
{{Economics_Lectures}}
 
{{Economics_Lectures}}
 +
Much of this lecture is devoted to review, and we also learn about the powerful Coase theorem.  The homework this week includes a quiz that covers the entire course so far.
  
Fifth Lecture – Short Run Output, also Coase Theorem
+
By now you may have noticed that there is a style to economics:  simple concepts are studied very carefully.  Patience is essential to solving economic problems correctly.  Unlike history or science, it helps in economics to be extremely careful when '''''first considering''''' a problem.  Haste or sloppiness at the outset of trying to solve a problem can lead to unnecessary mistakes. 
  
Instructor, Andy Schlafly
+
Economics consists of making simple observations about complex situations in order to derive powerful results.  There may be many things that are unknown or uncertain about a situation, but economics looks at what can be determined and then derives as much as possible from what is known.  For example, one might ask an economist what he can say about public school classes.  Most people might respond, "I can't say anything about them without knowing more information."  But an economist thinks about what can be said despite the lack of knowledge of all the details.  The economist might say that we do know this:  public school classes censor prayer and avoid discussion of the Bible.  From that simple observation, an economist might draw a powerful conclusion:  students are completely missing out on the central source of wisdom and comfort.
+
==Introduction==
+
  
We have talked about the concept of “equilibrium”, which is when the price and quantity settle down to their appropriate amounts after bouncing around for a while.  At equilibrium, supply price and quantity equal demand price and quantity.  But it may take time to get to equilibrium, with much trial and error in pricing in the meantime.
+
==Efficiency==
  
Last lecture we focused solely on “demand”This time we turn to “supply”We look at how companies decide how much product to make and put out into the marketHow many goods should a company produce, or how many services should it provide?
+
Imagine what your day is like as President of the widget factoryYou arrive to work earlier than everyone else, because you care the most about the success of your companyDuring the workday you walk through your factory to see how things are goingYou see employees chatting at the water cooler, talking to their friends on the phone, or not showing up for work at all.  This irritates you because you are paying for their time.  You tell them to get back to work.
  
Before we start, however, we define two terms essential to economics: the “short run” and the “long run. As its name implies, the “short run” is a relatively short period of time in which a company can only make temporary changes to its operationIn a sporting contest, the “short run” would during a game, when the coach decides to substitute his players or alter the game plan to try to win that particular contestDuring the “short run” only quick and temporary reactions by a company or firm to a fluctuation in demand are possible.  For example, changes like using more overtime labor would be a short run adjustment.  Or telling workers to take an extended vacation due to lack of demand for the goods would be another short run change.  This class we will be focusing on the “short run.
+
You also see equipment sitting idle for various reasonsThat annoys you tooYou paid for the equipment, or you are renting it, but it is not helping your business by sitting idleYou want to return or sell it, or find a way to make it useful.
  
In the “short run” it is impossible to change the fixed costs, or “sunk costs. The cost of factory, and the equipment inside, cannot be altered.  These fixed costs can be easily measured by seeing what the total costs are when output is zeroThat is because when output is zero, there are no marginal costs, and all the costs are the fixed ones.
+
Less easy to see are the wasted opportunity costs.  Perhaps your assembly line could be making a different kind of widget that would be more profitable than the one you are making.   
  
The “long run” consists of a time period long enough to make basic and permanent changes, like building new factories, buying new equipment, and hiring and training new employees.  In a sporting contest, it would include scouting and drafting new players, or building a new weight roomEverything can be adjusted in the “long run”: workforce, facilities, materials, equipment, investment, etc.  We’ll discuss the “long run” next class.
+
All your concerns can be summed in one economic term: “efficiency”.  Efficiency is the maximum possible productivity at any given time.  It consists of the least amount of wasted time, effort or moneyThere is no wasted opportunity cost in an efficient operation.
  
For now, let’s focus on the “short run. The key concepts are “marginal cost” and “marginal revenue.”  How much does it cost to make one more widget, and much revenue does that extra widget generate for the company?  That additional cost per unit is called “marginal cost.”  The additional revenue per unit is called “marginal revenue.”  As long as marginal revenue is slightly higher than marginal cost, then it makes sense to produce that extra widget.  Typically, companies continue making more and more goods until marginal revenue falls below marginal cost, at which time they stop production because they begin to lose money on each additional good they produce.
+
This economic term (“efficiency”) has the same meaning as its common everyday usage“It was an inefficient use of my time to sit here all morning waiting for you!”  “Try to do your chores more efficiently so that you can finish sooner.”  “She finishes her homework faster than you because she works more efficiently.
  
We will not spend this entire class on marginal cost and revenueWe are also going to introduce two other concepts basic to modern economics: efficiency and the Coase TheoremYou’ll find those topics extremely interestingHowever, let’s cover the basics first.
+
Generally, maximum efficiency is desired and people want to avoid wasted time, materials, effort, and expenseHowever, there is a significant obstacle to true efficiency: transaction costs.  Recall that “transaction costs” are all the incidental expenses that a consumer must spend to acquire a goodOne textbook defines transaction costs as “the time, effort, and expense that go into the purchase of a good.”<ref>Spencer, ''Contemporary Economics'', at p. D-53.</ref> Nobel laureate Ronald Coase, discussed later in this lecture, describes “transaction costs” as simply the “costs of using the market.
+
==The Short Run==
+
  
Imagine yourself as the President of a company making widgets, our imaginary good.  If it costs you $200 to make 10 widgets and $205 to make 11 widgets, then what is your marginal cost (MC) of the 11th unit?  It is only $5.  What is its average cost?  Nearly $19 ($205 total cost divided by 11 total units).  Average cost is often greater than the marginal costThis makes sense, because once you pay for your factory and workers, you do not have much additional cost to produce an extra unit.  This is called economies of scale: the bigger your operation, the cheaper you can make one more unit.
+
If you love the homemade ice cream at your favorite restaurant, then you have to spend the time and money driving there, waiting for a table, tipping the waitress, paying the sales tax, etcAll you wanted was the homemade ice cream, but many transaction costs stand in the way of a perfectly efficient transaction.
  
Think of a baking some breadIt requires some time and effort to bake one loaf of bread.  But there is not as much extra effort to stick another loaf in the oven.
+
One day you may want to buy a houseIdeally, you would like to drive up to the house you want and pay the owner directly, and then move in.  But in reality, there are transaction costs in buying a house.  These include finding what you want, bargaining over the price, paying a real estate broker and attorney, and so on.  Those transaction costs drive up the price of the house, and create inefficiencies.  Some additional transaction costs are imposed by governmental regulations.
  
Or imagine going to a baseball game.  The cost for one person to go is the ticket price plus the cost of gas and parking and wear and tear on the car.  The cost for a second person to go with the first person is just the price of the ticket.  There is no extra gas or parking or wear and tear on the car for a second person to ride along.  So the marginal cost for the second person is much less than for the first person.
+
== Review: Elasticity ==
  
But let’s return to your role as President of the widget companyYou are deciding how many employees to hire. You have an assembly line that needs workers.  Each additional employee that you hire to work on that assembly line increases the “marginal product of labor,” which is the increase in output for each additional unit of labor. It is often called “MP”.
+
In Lecture Three we learned about "elasticity"Let's define it again: '''''elasticity is the responsiveness in demand for a particular good due to changes in a variable such price or income'''''.<ref>There is also an elasticity '''''of supply''''' of a particular good that we'll mention below.</ref>
  
Let’s explain MP a different way to make sure you understand it.  The more workers you hire, the more goods your company can produce.  Suppose you can make 1000 widgets a week with 10 employees.  Then you hire one more employee, and your output increases to 1015 widgets.  What is the “marginal product of labor,” or MP, for your 11th employee?  It is 1015-1000=15Note that is less than the average product of labor, which 1015/11 = 92.3 for 11 employees.  You are suffering from “diminishing marginal returns.”  You received much more benefit from the 1-10 employees you hired earlier (their average product of labor is 100) than this 11th employee (with its MP of only 15).
+
The concept of elasticity is worth learning wellMany questions on an economics exam (such as the CLEP) ask about elasticity.
  
Again, this makes sense.  As you hire more and more employees, your benefit from will eventually decline.  Once the assembly line has enough workers to satisfy demand, for example, you would be wasting money by hiring additional workers.  They would end up spending the day talking to each other rather than doing productive work.  If you were to keep hiring employees, then eventually the MP for your next employee would fall to zero.  He would have nothing productive to do.
+
There are two types of elasticity of demand:
  
On the other side, however, the MP for your first employee would be greater than zero.  Additional employees might have even higher MPs because you are filling your assembly line.  If your assembly line needs 10 employees to run it, then the MP for your 10th employee will the highest of all.  After that, the MP begins falling.
+
*price elasticity of demand
 +
*income elasticity of demand
  
In general, MP rises as your initial employees are hired, eventually reaches a maximum at some point and then falls back towards zero for each additional employee.  It is an upside-down oval, beginning at MP=0 for 0 employees and returning to MP=0 for a large number “n” of employees.  The value of “n” depends on the business.   
+
Keep these different types of elasticity separate: price elasticity is the change in demand due to a change in the price of the good, while income elasticity is the change in demand due to a change in the income of the buyer.   
  
The optimal number of employees for an NBA basketball team, when MP is its maximum, is only about a dozen players.  The optimal number of employees for Wal-Mart, when MP is its maximum, is over 1 million employees.  So it all depends on what the company is producing.
+
=== Price Elasticity (review) ===
  
Can we can find the marginal cost (MC) of making that extra widget based on (i) the wages we have to pay the extra employee and (ii) his marginal productivity (MP)If it costs us $100 to hire one more employee, and he enables us to make 10 more widgets, then our marginal cost (MC) is simply $100/10 = $10 per unitIn other words, MC = wage/MP.
+
'''''Price''''' elasticity of demand is the change in the quantity demanded by the public for a particular good due to a change in its '''''price'''''.  Its symbol is "Ped", for "Price elasticity of demand."  This term is used to answer this question:  if the price of gasoline increases, how does the demand for gasoline changeIt decreases due to the Law of Demand, but the '''''price elasticity''''' tells us '''''how much''''' it decreases due to a price increase.  Specifically, price elasticity is the percentage change in quantity demanded, divided by the percentage change in the price of the good.  If the percent change in quantity demanded is more than the percent change in price, then the good is considered "elastic"If the percent change in quantity demanded is less than the percent change in price, then the good is considered "inelastic".  The Law of Demand means that price elasticity is always negative, but for convenience everyone uses the absolute value (positive value) without the minus sign.
  
Let’s make sure we understand this by looking at another example.  Suppose that hiring one more sales agent at $80 per day in our clothing store enables us to sell 8 more dressesWhat is our marginal cost for dresses at that point?  It is simply the additional cost of $80 (the wage) divided by that employee’s marginal productivity of 8 new sales, yielding a marginal cost of $10 per dress.
+
Price elasticity of demand is important because it tells us whether the owner's
 +
overall revenue goes up or down due to a price changeRevenue is price times quantity, and when price goes up then quantity goes down, and we need to know the price elasticity to know what happens to the overall '''P x Q''' (price times quantity, which is the revenue).
  
==Efficiency==
+
Mathematically, price elasticity is as follows:
  
Imagine what your day is like as President of the widget factory.  You arrive to work earlier than everyone else, because you care the most about the success of your company.  During the workday you walk through your factory to see how things are going.  You see employees chatting at the water cooler, talking to their friends on the phone, or not showing up for work at all.  This irritates you because you are paying for their time.  You tell them to get back to work.
+
:<math>Ped = \frac{% \Delta (\mbox{Quantity demanded of good})}{% \Delta (\mbox{Price change in good})}</math>
  
You also see equipment sitting idle for various reasons.  That annoys you too.  You paid for the equipment, or you are renting it, but it is not helping your business by sitting idle.  You want to return or sell it, or find a way to make it useful.
+
=== Cross Elasticity ===
  
Less easy to see are the wasted opportunity costsPerhaps your assembly line could be making a different kind of widget that would be more profitable than the one you are making.   
+
Once you fully understand price elasticity of demand, then it is easy to understand the concept of "cross elasticity of demand." Cross elasticity of demand is the percent change in demand of '''''one good''''' due to a change in the price of a '''''different good'''''.  The two goods are either substitutes or complements for each other, which makes their cross elasticity usefulThe symbol for cross elasticity of demand is "Xed", with "X" representing the "cross" and "ed" representing the "elasticity of demand."
  
All your concerns can be summed in one economic term: “efficiency”.  Efficiency is the maximum possible productivity at any given time.  It consists of the least amount of wasted time, effort or money.  There is no wasted opportunity cost in an efficient operation.
+
Mathematically, cross elasticity is as follows:
  
For once, this is an economic term (“efficiency”) that has the same meaning as its common everyday usage.  “It was an inefficient use of my time to sit here all morning waiting for you!”  “Try to do your chores more efficiently so that you can finish sooner.”  “She finishes her homework faster than you because she works more efficiently.”
+
:<math>Xed = \frac{% \Delta (\mbox{Quantity demanded of good Y})}{% \Delta (\mbox{Price change in good X})}</math>
  
Generally, maximum efficiency is desired and people want to avoid wasted time, materials, effort, and expense.  However, there is a significant obstacle to true efficiency: transaction costs.  Recall that “transaction costs” are all the incidental expenses that a consumer must spend to acquire a good.  One textbook defines transaction costs as “the time, effort, and expense that go into the purchase of a good.”  (Spencer, Contemporary Economics, at p. D-53).  Nobel laureate Ronald Coase, discussed below, describes “transaction costs” as simply the “costs of using the market.”
+
'''''Note that cross elasticity is different from price elasticity in that cross elasticity is comparing the change in demand for one good in response to the change in price of another good'''''.
  
If you love the homemade ice cream at your favorite restaurant, then you have to spend the time and money driving there, waiting for a table, tipping the waitress, paying the sales tax, etcAll you wanted was the homemade ice cream, but many transaction costs stand in the way of a perfectly efficient transaction.
+
If the two goods (X and Y) are complements, then the cross elasticity is negative just as the price elasticity of a good is.  Ketchup is a complement for french fries, and if the price of french fries increases, then people will eat fewer french fries and less ketchupHence the demand for ketchup will decrease and its cross elasticity with respect to french fries is negative.
  
One day you may want to buy a house.  Ideally, you would like to drive up to the house you want and pay the owner directly, and then move inBut in reality, there are enormous transaction costs in buying a house.  These include finding what you want, bargaining over the price, paying the real estate broker and attorney, and so onThose transaction costs drive up the price of the house, and create inefficiencies.
+
If the two goods (X and Y) are substitutes, then the cross elasticity is positivePotato chips are a substitute for french fries, and if the price of french fries increases, then people will eat fewer french fries and more potato chipsHence the demand for potato chips will increase and its cross elasticity with respect to french fries is positive.
  
Some transaction costs are imposed by governmental regulations.  In many areas, homeowners must receive permission to chop down trees on their yards or build an addition.  The time and expense in obtaining that approval by the local zoning board are transaction costs.
+
Expect a question on an exam which provides two goods and asks whether their cross elasticity is positive or negative.  The correct answer will depend on whether the goods are complements (then the answer is "negative") or substitutes (then the answer is "positive").
  
==A Brief Look at Law and Economics==
+
=== Income Elasticity (review) ===
  
We live in what is known as the “regulatory state.”  The government regulates almost every aspect of business.  It is even worse in most other countriesIn many industries, the government tells business how much they can charge, how much they can pollute, how much they have to pay their employees, and so onGovernment has even more regulations for itself, regulating nearly every aspect of hiring and firing government employees and doling out benefits to the public.
+
'''''Income''''' elasticity of demand is the change in the quantity demanded by the public for a particular good due to a change in '''''income'''''Stated another way, income elasticity is the responsiveness in demand for a good due to a change in the buyers' incomeIts symbol is "Yed", because "Y" is a symbol for income, and "ed" refers to "elasticity of demand.
  
The vision of many liberals has been to gain control of the economy and limit free enterprise by imposing rules about who owns what property and how it can be usedThe law defines who holds what rights and liabilities, and business often consists of exchanging money for those rights. For example, the law says that Disney continues to own a copyright in Mickey Mouse, even though it was created about 75 years ago.  People who want to use the image of Mickey Mouse must pay Disney money because of the legal rule.
+
In calculating elasticity, the numerator is the same for both price and income elasticity:  it is the percent change in quantity demanded for the goodBut the denominator is different for these two elasticities: the denominator for price elasticity is the percent change in price of the good, while the denominator for income elasticity is the percent change in income for the buyers.
  
To take another example, states tried to eliminate people from welfare when they felt it was no longer needed or desirablePeople eliminated from welfare sued, demanding a formal hearing on their “rights” to welfare before being eliminatedIn a U.S. Supreme Court case entitled Goldberg v. Kelly (1970), the Court agreed with the welfare recipients and created a constitutional right to a hearing prior to be removed from a welfare programCan you think of a purely economic argument against that requirement?
+
Unlike price elasticity, income elasticity can be either positive or negative, depending on the goodFor a "normal" good, income elasticity is positive; for an "inferior" good, it is negative.  Inferior goods are rare: they have a decrease in demand when income by the public increases.  Usually demand for goods increase as income by the public increases, hence the name "normal good" to describe them. 
 +
 
 +
Normal goods are necessities or luxuries, depending on their elasticity:  necessities are inelastic (elasticity less than 1), and luxuries are elastic (elasticity greater than 1)Notice that "necessity" and "luxury" goods are defined in terms of '''''income''''' elasticity, not in terms of '''''price''''' elasticity.
 +
 
 +
This table is a useful study guide for income elasticity:
 +
 
 +
{| class="wikitable"
 +
|-
 +
!Yed
 +
!Normal or Inferior?
 +
!Elastic or Inelastic?
 +
!Necessity or Luxury?
 +
|-
 +
|Yed = -0.5
 +
|inferior
 +
|inelastic
 +
|neither necessity nor luxury
 +
|-
 +
|Yed = 0.6
 +
|normal
 +
|inelastic
 +
|necessity
 +
|-
 +
|Yed = -1.9
 +
|inferior
 +
|elastic
 +
|neither necessity nor luxury
 +
|-
 +
|Yed = 3.5
 +
|normal
 +
|elastic
 +
|luxury
 +
|-
 +
|}
 +
 
 +
Mathematically, income elasticity is as follows:
 +
 
 +
:<math>Yed = \frac{% \Delta (\mbox{Quantity demanded of good})}{% \Delta (\mbox{Change in income of buyers of good})}</math>
 +
 
 +
=== Supply Elasticity ===
 +
 
 +
One more and we're done.  The price elasticity of '''''supply''''' is the percent change in quantity supplied divided by the percent change in price for the good.  Mathematically, that is:
 +
 
 +
:<math>Pes = \frac{% \Delta (\mbox{Quantity supplied of good})}{% \Delta (\mbox{Price change in good})}</math>
 +
 
 +
If the supply elasticity (Pes) is inelastic (less than 1), then it is difficult for suppliers to react quickly to a change in price.  If Pes is elastic (more than 1), then suppliers can react quickly to a change in price, as in supplying more goods when the price increases.
 +
 
 +
== Marginal Cost and Marginal Revenue ==
 +
 
 +
Two of the most important concepts in economics are '''''marginal cost''''' and '''''marginal revenue'''''.
 +
 
 +
'''''Marginal cost''''' is the additional cost to produce '''''one more unit'''''.  It includes only the additional cost, and not any costs to produce anything else.  If, for example, you drove to the grocery store and then saw another store a half mile up the road, the marginal cost of driving to that store would be only the additional gas and time and wear and tear on the car for going the extra half mile.  The marginal cost would not include the original cost of the car, or taking off time from work, or anything other than the extra cost of going that extra half mile.
 +
 
 +
Similarly, the '''''marginal revenue''''' is the additional revenue received by a business from selling '''''one more unit'''''It equals the price of the unit, because revenue is '''P x Q''', and for one more unit Q (quantity) is 1.
 +
 
 +
Imagine yourself as an owner of a business.  As long as marginal revenue is larger than marginal cost, then you will want to sell more and more units.  But once marginal revenue falls just below your marginal cost, then you lose money for each additional unit.  You will lose money in selling more goods at that point.
 +
 
 +
An owner sells as many goods as he can until marginal revenue decreases to the level of his marginal cost.  At that point he does not make any more money selling goods, and he stops selling additional goods.
 +
 
 +
Example:  a grocery store owner considers how late he should keep his store open at night.  His marginal cost includes electricity and wages for employees.  His marginal revenue includes the groceries purchased by the late-night shoppers.  Once the volume of groceries late at night decreases to the point where his marginal revenue from those sales dips below his marginal cost for keeping the store open, he closes his store for the night.
  
 
==The Coase Theorem==
 
==The Coase Theorem==
  
There is a remarkable economist named [[Ronald Coase]], who is now over 95 years oldHe is responsible for perhaps the single greatest economic insight of the past fifty years, for which he won an entire Nobel prize in 1991 (most Nobel prize awards are shared among multiple recipients, but not this one).
+
The most-cited article in all of economics<ref name="Coase article">http://www.boston.com/globe/search/stories/nobel/1991/1991i.html</ref> is “The Problem of Social Cost,” published by Professor Ronald H. Coase in 1960.  It describes what later became known as the “Coase theorem,” a fundamental conservative insight about entitlements and property rightsThough criticized for thirty years by professors who disliked its implications, this theorem was finally recognized by the 1991 Nobel Prize of Economics, of which Professor Coase was the sole recipient.  (An unshared Nobel Prize awarded to only one recipient is rare.) Some oppose this theorem, despite its truth, and economists have even called Professor Coase names in criticism.<ref name="Coase article"/>
  
It is worth reading an interview of him, particularly from the beginning through the discussion of his “Coase Theorem”:
+
===The Coase Theorem Explained===
http://reason.com/9701/int.coase.shtml
+
  
Coase had a physical handicap and did not attend regular schoolA high percentage of great thinkers and businessmen, in fact, did not go through the formal schooling systemThey learned to think for themselves rather than conform to the government’s way of thinking.
+
Like Isaac Newton, who invented calculus in order to do his work on physics, Ronald Coase first invented the new concept of “transaction costs” to lay the groundwork for his insightAs we have explained, “transaction costs” consist of the time, money, and effort someone loses in obtaining what he wantsLaw professor Richard Epstein tersely summed up the meaning of “transaction costs” in one word:  “friction.”<ref name="Coase article"/> Coase’s Nobel Prize was partly based on his discovery and development of this new concept, and the committee conferring the prize (the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences) likened this to the discovery of a new set of elementary particles in physics.  
  
Coase started out thinking that government control (socialism) was good, but he thought some more for himself and became a supporter of the free marketHe ended up at the University of Chicago, one of the few universities that is friendly to free market economists.
+
Once “transaction costs” were discovered and described, Coase’s insight became possible.  '''''The Coase theorem states that in the absence of transaction costs, an efficient or optimal economic result occurs regardless of who owns the property rights.''''' The free market guarantees the efficient outcome regardless of who owns what, because there are incentives to bargain towards the efficient result until it is achieved.  This is true even for activities that generate “negative externalities” (harm to others); freedom to negotiate will enable all affected to bargain towards the most efficient output.
  
Coase’s work in economics almost never mentioned a single mathematical equation or formula.  His insight is simply restated, but takes a long time to understand.  Most esteemed economists, such as Milton Friedman, were initially adamant that Ronald Coase was wrong in his statement.  But Coase was right and everyone else was wrong.  Friedman, to his credit, admitted his own mistake and began teaching and lecturing about the Coase Theorem.
+
Restated another way, if property rights are well-defined and transaction costs are zero, then the most efficient or optimal economic activity will occur regardless of who holds the rights, because negotiation and market transactions will ensure the optimal allocation and use of property in a free market.
  
Coase’s brilliant observation was as followsHe said that, in the absence of transaction costs, there is the same amount of desired economic activity regardless of who owns the legal rights or property or money. There will be the same number of images of Mickey Mouse regardless of whether Disney still owns the copyright or notThe same number of fans will attend New York Yankees baseball games regardless of whether George Steinbrenner owns the seats at Yankee stadium or 57,478 random members of the public do.  The same amount of Microsoft products will sell regardless of whether Bill Gates is the richest or poorest person in the world.
+
Chicago federal trial judge Milton Shadur explained the legal meaning of this theorem“So long as the rule of law is known when parties act, the ultimate economic result is the same no matter which way the law has resolved the issue.”<ref>''Coltman v. Commissioner'', 980 F.2d 1134, 1137 (7th Cir. 1992).</ref> Whether the law gives an entitlement to a rich man or a poor one, the economic activity will be the same, assuming people can bargain freely with each other.
  
[[Ralph Waldo Emerson]] once said, “Build a better mousetrap and the world will beat a path to your door.” In the absence of transaction costs, it does not matter if you are rich or poor in determining how many will buy the mousetrap and what they will pay for it.  The economic activity of selling mousetraps is determined by how desirable the mousetrap itself is, not who owns rights to it or how wealthy the inventor is.  The person who owns the mousetrap will profit from it if it is better than the competition, but the same number of mousetraps will sell regardless of who owns it.
+
An oversimplification of this concept is Ralph Waldo Emerson’s famous statement that if a man can “make a better mouse-trap … [then] the world will make a beaten path to his door.”   Assuming people can buy and sell without regulatory or other barriers, it does not matter who invents the mousetrap or who obtains legal rights to it.  The free market will ensure that the better mousetrap is sold to the public for the benefit of all involved.  
  
This observation of Coase (and Emerson) is true only when there are no transaction costs.  That means there is no time or expense lost in bargaining, or finding the mousetrap in the first place.  No advertising expenses, for example.  No incidental expenses can exist in connection with buying a good or serviceUsing these assumptions, people get what they want with additional expense, and trade however they like without further costAlthough it may seem unrealistic to assume there are no transaction costs, it is very useful to start with this premise.  Some activities, like trading stocks over the internet, do have very little transaction costs.
+
The meaning of Coase’s insight for government regulation was clear. A society is better off by simply assigning property rights, reducing transaction costs, and getting out of the way so that the market process can reach its most efficient resultGovernment regulations that add transaction costs hurt efficiency and prosperityIn response to the question “What’s an example of bad regulation?,” Coase replied, “I can’t remember one that’s good.
  
The Coase Theorem is easy to state. With some reflection, everyone can understand it.  But you have to think about it a great deal to grasp it.  It will help you understand what the free market really is.  The implications of the Coase Theorem are indeed extraordinary.  Its effects are still being felt.
+
===The Most Famous Dinner in the History of Economics<ref>Warsh D., ''Knowledge and the Wealth of Nations: A Story of Economic Discovery'' 299 (2006).</ref>===
  
Homework questions will explore some of the consequencesBut here is one example to start you in the right direction.  Suppose the government of the State of Massachusetts heard that Ralph Waldo Emerson built a better mousetrap and many people were beating a path to his door to buy itThe government then seized the rights to the mousetrap and auctioned those rights off to the highest bidder, pocketing the cashAfterwards, will more or less mousetraps be sold?  The exact same number will be soldIt doesn’t matter who owns the mousetrap (assuming transaction costs are zero).
+
Initially Professor Coase’s theory was criticized, even by economistsIn 1959 Coase, then in the economics department at the University of Virginia, published an early version in an article concerning allocation of the radio frequency spectrumCoase proposed that the Federal Communications Commission reject its bureaucratic procedures for assigning licenses and simply sell frequencies in the spectrum to the highest biddersCoase elaborated on his theory in his article, but every economist at the University of Chicago objectedEven though the Chicago economists were predisposed towards free markets, they thought Coase had erred.  
  
==Assignment==
+
These economists wanted the truth, and they invited Coase to a friendly dinner at the home of a conservative economist named Aaron Director.  Milton Friedman and George Stigler were among those in attendance who thought Coase had erred.  When hors d’oeuvres were served, the vote was 20 against Coase’s theory and only Coase in favor of it. As the two-hour discussion proceeded, it became like a scene from the famous movie ''12 Angry Men''.  One by one, bit by bit, the great economists came over to Coase’s side as their objections were resolved.  By the end their leader, Milton Friedman himself heroically admitted that he had been wrong and Coase was right.  To his enormous credit, Professor Friedman then became an energetic champion of Coase’s theory.
  
Read and, if necessary, reread the above lecture. Then answer these questions:
+
The dinner attendees thanked Coase and invited him to write up his theory more fully for a new publication called the ''Journal of Law and Economics'', and Coase's article became the most cited paper in all of economics.
  
===Introductory===
+
=== The Man Behind the Coase Theorem ===
 +
 
 +
Who is this man behind this revelation?  It took an unconventional education to bring forth this insightful work.  Professor Ronald Coase, born in 1910 in England, suffered from a physical handicap as a youngster and thus could not attend regular school.  He had to wear leg braces and was eventually enrolled in a school for “physical defectives.”  But that school was managed by the same organization that ran the school for “mental defectives,” and Coase later explained that there was “some overlapping in the curriculum.”<ref>http://www.reason.com/news/printer/30115.html</ref> As a result, Coase spent his days in basket-weaving classes, and was deprived of any formal academic instruction until age 10.
 +
 
 +
He eventually found his way to the London School of Economics, where he was a socialist until his senior year, when he enrolled in a seminar taught by Professor Arnold Plant.  That course was devoted to the “invisible hand” and featured stimulating discussions without any readings.  It changed Coase’s life, as he embraced the power of the free market.
 +
 
 +
Later he emigrated to the United States and eventually joined the faculty at the University of Chicago.  His work almost never included a mathematical equation or formula, contrary to the modern trend in economics.  To this day many in the field of law and economics, which Coase helped found, pursue quantification that he would never have done himself.
 +
 
 +
Professor Coase’s breakthrough was analogous to that of mathematician Kurt Gödel.  Both deflated the arrogance of their colleagues, and as a result both received a chilly reception from their peers.
 +
 
 +
===Implications of the Coase Theorem===
 +
 
 +
In public policy, the Coase theorem implies that greater efficiency and prosperity can be obtained by reducing and eliminating transaction costs.  Bureaucratic hurdles erected by government and the legal system increase transaction costs and reduce efficiency and prosperity.  Society as a whole would be better off if transaction costs were minimized.  Wealth is lost by impeding the ability of people to negotiate private contracts among themselves.  The role of government to increase prosperity should focus on lowering transaction costs, not raising them.
 +
 
 +
Transaction costs are particularly large in health care, where patients and physicians must waste massive amounts of time determining how much a procedure costs, whether a third party will pay for it, and obtaining payment from that third party (such as government or an insurance company).  In some cases the transaction costs are even infinite, as bureaucrats try to prohibit private contracts entirely for legitimate services.  Canada forbids paying privately for medical services, requiring everyone to depend on government controls.
 +
 
 +
The Coase theorem demonstrates that these transaction costs detract from overall wealth and efficient economic behavior.  Legal impediments to private contracting for medical services should be removed, as such interference frustrates the ability to reach economically optimal results.  The best that government can do in controlling medical costs is simply to remove the transaction costs and get out of the way so that the parties, patients and physicians can negotiate optimal arrangements.
 +
 
 +
The Coase theorem also provides economic justification for adhering to Rule of Law, and rejecting an “evolving” Constitution.  As Judge Shadur observed above, as long as there is a clear Rule of Law it does not matter to prosperity where that rule assigns the rights.  Often the best courts can do is embrace the Rule of Law, and then get out of the way.  Changing rules midstream, as in arbitrarily taking one’s property,  is economically harmful.
 +
 
 +
There are mind-bending implications of the Coase theorem.  Money itself is a property right, and that property will also be allocated to its most efficient uses regardless of who controls it, assuming rational behavior and no transaction costs.  Judge Shadur explained above that the Coase theorem means “the ultimate economic result is the same no matter which way the law has resolved the issue,” and likewise the economic result is the same no matter which rational person has the property right to the wealth.  Bill Gates may control $100 billion or so, but the best use of that money is dictated by demand in the free market.  If Gates decides to spend the money in a way contrary to its most efficient uses in the free market, then he is wasting his own money and it is his loss.
 +
 
 +
The Coase theorem even justifies the famous observation by Jesus that we “will always have the poor among” us.  Attempts by government to reduce the gap between the rich and the poor result in more transaction costs, which prevent future success.  These transaction costs include higher taxes and greater regulation.  The more transaction costs are injected into the system, the more inefficient it becomes, and society is worse off overall.  The only way government can eliminate the poor (relative to the rich) is by imposing transaction costs that make everyone poorer.  Redistributing wealth is like using a leaky bucket to transfer water from one place to another.
 +
 
 +
==Assignment==
  
1.  Your boss asked you to work overtimeIs that a short-run or long-run solution for him?
+
Read and, if necessary, reread the above lectureThen answer the following six questions:
  
2. Explain briefly economic “efficiency”Give an example of something that is efficient, and something else that is not.
+
1. Suppose the cross elasticity of demand for goods A and B is +3.8, and for goods X and Y is -2.7What can you conclude about the relationship of the goods A and B, and of X and Y (i.e., are they substitutes or complements)?
  
===Intermediate===
+
2.  Suppose it costs you $500 to make each of your first 5 units, then $200 to make each of your next 5 units, and then $100 to make each of your next 5 units.  Costs do not decrease further for you.  What is the marginal cost for you to make another unit, after you have made 15 units?  What is your overall average cost per unit after you make your 16th unit?  Compare the two and comment on how whether they are equal, and why.
  
4. Your widget company has the following costs: Producing 10 widgets, your costs are $2000.  Producing 8 widgets, your costs are $1800.  Producing 6 widgets, your costs are $1500Producing 4 widgets, your costs are $1200Producing 2 widgets, your costs are $800.  Producing 0 widgets, your costs are $400.  What is your fixed cost?  What is your MC for widgets 7 & 8?  What are your average costs for producing 4 widgets?
+
3. Suppose your annual income increases from $20,000 to $25,000Suppose your demand for steak increases by 10% and your demand for fast food hamburgers decreases by 5%Which type of goods are steak, and which type are hamburgers?
  
5A regulator had to choose new regulation A or B: (A) imposed substantial new transaction costs on consumers, while (B) did not.  Which option would the Coase Theorem tend to prefer?  Say why.
+
4What does an owner do when his marginal revenue exceeds his marginal cost?  Explain, including what will eventually happen to the marginal revenue compared with the marginal cost for the owner.
  
6.   Explain why a businessman fixes his production or supply of goods at the point where his marginal cost equals his marginal revenue.
+
5. What does the Coase theorem say about the desirability, and the effect, of government regulations that increase transaction costs?
  
7Explain the difference between marginal cost and average cost.
+
6Take the online 10-question quiz at www.conservaget.com .  This quiz covers the basic concepts learned in our entire course so far.  If you have a smart phone such as an iPhone or Android, this quiz should work on that too.  Your score is recorded electronically but also include the score as your answer to this question (e.g., 8 out of 10).
+
===Honors===
+
  
Write a 300-word essay on one or more of the following:
+
== Honors ==
  
10Democratic politicians complain about the gap between the rich and poor.  Would the economy work any better if the gap were smaller?  Assume the absence of transaction costs.
+
7Write a brief (100 words is fine) essay about an implication or consequence of the Coase theorem.
  
11.  The [[Fifth Amendment]] says “nor shall private property be taken for public use, without just compensation.”  How does that benefit the economy?
+
== References ==
  
12.  “The pen is mightier than the sword.”  Assuming that the sword is used mainly to seize property, explain a purely economic justification for that statement.
+
<references/>
  
[[Category:Economics]]
+
[[Category:Economics lectures]]
 +
{{DEFAULTSORT: Economics Lecture 05}}

Latest revision as of 19:20, March 20, 2013

Economics Lectures - [1 - 2 - 3 - 4 - 5 - 6 - 7 - 8 - 9 - 10 - 11 - 12 - 13 - 14]

Much of this lecture is devoted to review, and we also learn about the powerful Coase theorem. The homework this week includes a quiz that covers the entire course so far.

By now you may have noticed that there is a style to economics: simple concepts are studied very carefully. Patience is essential to solving economic problems correctly. Unlike history or science, it helps in economics to be extremely careful when first considering a problem. Haste or sloppiness at the outset of trying to solve a problem can lead to unnecessary mistakes.

Economics consists of making simple observations about complex situations in order to derive powerful results. There may be many things that are unknown or uncertain about a situation, but economics looks at what can be determined and then derives as much as possible from what is known. For example, one might ask an economist what he can say about public school classes. Most people might respond, "I can't say anything about them without knowing more information." But an economist thinks about what can be said despite the lack of knowledge of all the details. The economist might say that we do know this: public school classes censor prayer and avoid discussion of the Bible. From that simple observation, an economist might draw a powerful conclusion: students are completely missing out on the central source of wisdom and comfort.

Efficiency

Imagine what your day is like as President of the widget factory. You arrive to work earlier than everyone else, because you care the most about the success of your company. During the workday you walk through your factory to see how things are going. You see employees chatting at the water cooler, talking to their friends on the phone, or not showing up for work at all. This irritates you because you are paying for their time. You tell them to get back to work.

You also see equipment sitting idle for various reasons. That annoys you too. You paid for the equipment, or you are renting it, but it is not helping your business by sitting idle. You want to return or sell it, or find a way to make it useful.

Less easy to see are the wasted opportunity costs. Perhaps your assembly line could be making a different kind of widget that would be more profitable than the one you are making.

All your concerns can be summed in one economic term: “efficiency”. Efficiency is the maximum possible productivity at any given time. It consists of the least amount of wasted time, effort or money. There is no wasted opportunity cost in an efficient operation.

This economic term (“efficiency”) has the same meaning as its common everyday usage. “It was an inefficient use of my time to sit here all morning waiting for you!” “Try to do your chores more efficiently so that you can finish sooner.” “She finishes her homework faster than you because she works more efficiently.”

Generally, maximum efficiency is desired and people want to avoid wasted time, materials, effort, and expense. However, there is a significant obstacle to true efficiency: transaction costs. Recall that “transaction costs” are all the incidental expenses that a consumer must spend to acquire a good. One textbook defines transaction costs as “the time, effort, and expense that go into the purchase of a good.”[1] Nobel laureate Ronald Coase, discussed later in this lecture, describes “transaction costs” as simply the “costs of using the market.”

If you love the homemade ice cream at your favorite restaurant, then you have to spend the time and money driving there, waiting for a table, tipping the waitress, paying the sales tax, etc. All you wanted was the homemade ice cream, but many transaction costs stand in the way of a perfectly efficient transaction.

One day you may want to buy a house. Ideally, you would like to drive up to the house you want and pay the owner directly, and then move in. But in reality, there are transaction costs in buying a house. These include finding what you want, bargaining over the price, paying a real estate broker and attorney, and so on. Those transaction costs drive up the price of the house, and create inefficiencies. Some additional transaction costs are imposed by governmental regulations.

Review: Elasticity

In Lecture Three we learned about "elasticity". Let's define it again: elasticity is the responsiveness in demand for a particular good due to changes in a variable such price or income.[2]

The concept of elasticity is worth learning well. Many questions on an economics exam (such as the CLEP) ask about elasticity.

There are two types of elasticity of demand:

  • price elasticity of demand
  • income elasticity of demand

Keep these different types of elasticity separate: price elasticity is the change in demand due to a change in the price of the good, while income elasticity is the change in demand due to a change in the income of the buyer.

Price Elasticity (review)

Price elasticity of demand is the change in the quantity demanded by the public for a particular good due to a change in its price. Its symbol is "Ped", for "Price elasticity of demand." This term is used to answer this question: if the price of gasoline increases, how does the demand for gasoline change? It decreases due to the Law of Demand, but the price elasticity tells us how much it decreases due to a price increase. Specifically, price elasticity is the percentage change in quantity demanded, divided by the percentage change in the price of the good. If the percent change in quantity demanded is more than the percent change in price, then the good is considered "elastic". If the percent change in quantity demanded is less than the percent change in price, then the good is considered "inelastic". The Law of Demand means that price elasticity is always negative, but for convenience everyone uses the absolute value (positive value) without the minus sign.

Price elasticity of demand is important because it tells us whether the owner's overall revenue goes up or down due to a price change. Revenue is price times quantity, and when price goes up then quantity goes down, and we need to know the price elasticity to know what happens to the overall P x Q (price times quantity, which is the revenue).

Mathematically, price elasticity is as follows:

Cross Elasticity

Once you fully understand price elasticity of demand, then it is easy to understand the concept of "cross elasticity of demand." Cross elasticity of demand is the percent change in demand of one good due to a change in the price of a different good. The two goods are either substitutes or complements for each other, which makes their cross elasticity useful. The symbol for cross elasticity of demand is "Xed", with "X" representing the "cross" and "ed" representing the "elasticity of demand."

Mathematically, cross elasticity is as follows:

Note that cross elasticity is different from price elasticity in that cross elasticity is comparing the change in demand for one good in response to the change in price of another good.

If the two goods (X and Y) are complements, then the cross elasticity is negative just as the price elasticity of a good is. Ketchup is a complement for french fries, and if the price of french fries increases, then people will eat fewer french fries and less ketchup. Hence the demand for ketchup will decrease and its cross elasticity with respect to french fries is negative.

If the two goods (X and Y) are substitutes, then the cross elasticity is positive. Potato chips are a substitute for french fries, and if the price of french fries increases, then people will eat fewer french fries and more potato chips. Hence the demand for potato chips will increase and its cross elasticity with respect to french fries is positive.

Expect a question on an exam which provides two goods and asks whether their cross elasticity is positive or negative. The correct answer will depend on whether the goods are complements (then the answer is "negative") or substitutes (then the answer is "positive").

Income Elasticity (review)

Income elasticity of demand is the change in the quantity demanded by the public for a particular good due to a change in income. Stated another way, income elasticity is the responsiveness in demand for a good due to a change in the buyers' income. Its symbol is "Yed", because "Y" is a symbol for income, and "ed" refers to "elasticity of demand."

In calculating elasticity, the numerator is the same for both price and income elasticity: it is the percent change in quantity demanded for the good. But the denominator is different for these two elasticities: the denominator for price elasticity is the percent change in price of the good, while the denominator for income elasticity is the percent change in income for the buyers.

Unlike price elasticity, income elasticity can be either positive or negative, depending on the good. For a "normal" good, income elasticity is positive; for an "inferior" good, it is negative. Inferior goods are rare: they have a decrease in demand when income by the public increases. Usually demand for goods increase as income by the public increases, hence the name "normal good" to describe them.

Normal goods are necessities or luxuries, depending on their elasticity: necessities are inelastic (elasticity less than 1), and luxuries are elastic (elasticity greater than 1). Notice that "necessity" and "luxury" goods are defined in terms of income elasticity, not in terms of price elasticity.

This table is a useful study guide for income elasticity:

Yed Normal or Inferior? Elastic or Inelastic? Necessity or Luxury?
Yed = -0.5 inferior inelastic neither necessity nor luxury
Yed = 0.6 normal inelastic necessity
Yed = -1.9 inferior elastic neither necessity nor luxury
Yed = 3.5 normal elastic luxury

Mathematically, income elasticity is as follows:

Supply Elasticity

One more and we're done. The price elasticity of supply is the percent change in quantity supplied divided by the percent change in price for the good. Mathematically, that is:

If the supply elasticity (Pes) is inelastic (less than 1), then it is difficult for suppliers to react quickly to a change in price. If Pes is elastic (more than 1), then suppliers can react quickly to a change in price, as in supplying more goods when the price increases.

Marginal Cost and Marginal Revenue

Two of the most important concepts in economics are marginal cost and marginal revenue.

Marginal cost is the additional cost to produce one more unit. It includes only the additional cost, and not any costs to produce anything else. If, for example, you drove to the grocery store and then saw another store a half mile up the road, the marginal cost of driving to that store would be only the additional gas and time and wear and tear on the car for going the extra half mile. The marginal cost would not include the original cost of the car, or taking off time from work, or anything other than the extra cost of going that extra half mile.

Similarly, the marginal revenue is the additional revenue received by a business from selling one more unit. It equals the price of the unit, because revenue is P x Q, and for one more unit Q (quantity) is 1.

Imagine yourself as an owner of a business. As long as marginal revenue is larger than marginal cost, then you will want to sell more and more units. But once marginal revenue falls just below your marginal cost, then you lose money for each additional unit. You will lose money in selling more goods at that point.

An owner sells as many goods as he can until marginal revenue decreases to the level of his marginal cost. At that point he does not make any more money selling goods, and he stops selling additional goods.

Example: a grocery store owner considers how late he should keep his store open at night. His marginal cost includes electricity and wages for employees. His marginal revenue includes the groceries purchased by the late-night shoppers. Once the volume of groceries late at night decreases to the point where his marginal revenue from those sales dips below his marginal cost for keeping the store open, he closes his store for the night.

The Coase Theorem

The most-cited article in all of economics[3] is “The Problem of Social Cost,” published by Professor Ronald H. Coase in 1960. It describes what later became known as the “Coase theorem,” a fundamental conservative insight about entitlements and property rights. Though criticized for thirty years by professors who disliked its implications, this theorem was finally recognized by the 1991 Nobel Prize of Economics, of which Professor Coase was the sole recipient. (An unshared Nobel Prize awarded to only one recipient is rare.) Some oppose this theorem, despite its truth, and economists have even called Professor Coase names in criticism.[3]

The Coase Theorem Explained

Like Isaac Newton, who invented calculus in order to do his work on physics, Ronald Coase first invented the new concept of “transaction costs” to lay the groundwork for his insight. As we have explained, “transaction costs” consist of the time, money, and effort someone loses in obtaining what he wants. Law professor Richard Epstein tersely summed up the meaning of “transaction costs” in one word: “friction.”[3] Coase’s Nobel Prize was partly based on his discovery and development of this new concept, and the committee conferring the prize (the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences) likened this to the discovery of a new set of elementary particles in physics.

Once “transaction costs” were discovered and described, Coase’s insight became possible. The Coase theorem states that in the absence of transaction costs, an efficient or optimal economic result occurs regardless of who owns the property rights. The free market guarantees the efficient outcome regardless of who owns what, because there are incentives to bargain towards the efficient result until it is achieved. This is true even for activities that generate “negative externalities” (harm to others); freedom to negotiate will enable all affected to bargain towards the most efficient output.

Restated another way, if property rights are well-defined and transaction costs are zero, then the most efficient or optimal economic activity will occur regardless of who holds the rights, because negotiation and market transactions will ensure the optimal allocation and use of property in a free market.

Chicago federal trial judge Milton Shadur explained the legal meaning of this theorem. “So long as the rule of law is known when parties act, the ultimate economic result is the same no matter which way the law has resolved the issue.”[4] Whether the law gives an entitlement to a rich man or a poor one, the economic activity will be the same, assuming people can bargain freely with each other.

An oversimplification of this concept is Ralph Waldo Emerson’s famous statement that if a man can “make a better mouse-trap … [then] the world will make a beaten path to his door.” Assuming people can buy and sell without regulatory or other barriers, it does not matter who invents the mousetrap or who obtains legal rights to it. The free market will ensure that the better mousetrap is sold to the public for the benefit of all involved.

The meaning of Coase’s insight for government regulation was clear. A society is better off by simply assigning property rights, reducing transaction costs, and getting out of the way so that the market process can reach its most efficient result. Government regulations that add transaction costs hurt efficiency and prosperity. In response to the question “What’s an example of bad regulation?,” Coase replied, “I can’t remember one that’s good.”

The Most Famous Dinner in the History of Economics[5]

Initially Professor Coase’s theory was criticized, even by economists. In 1959 Coase, then in the economics department at the University of Virginia, published an early version in an article concerning allocation of the radio frequency spectrum. Coase proposed that the Federal Communications Commission reject its bureaucratic procedures for assigning licenses and simply sell frequencies in the spectrum to the highest bidders. Coase elaborated on his theory in his article, but every economist at the University of Chicago objected. Even though the Chicago economists were predisposed towards free markets, they thought Coase had erred.

These economists wanted the truth, and they invited Coase to a friendly dinner at the home of a conservative economist named Aaron Director. Milton Friedman and George Stigler were among those in attendance who thought Coase had erred. When hors d’oeuvres were served, the vote was 20 against Coase’s theory and only Coase in favor of it. As the two-hour discussion proceeded, it became like a scene from the famous movie 12 Angry Men. One by one, bit by bit, the great economists came over to Coase’s side as their objections were resolved. By the end their leader, Milton Friedman himself heroically admitted that he had been wrong and Coase was right. To his enormous credit, Professor Friedman then became an energetic champion of Coase’s theory.

The dinner attendees thanked Coase and invited him to write up his theory more fully for a new publication called the Journal of Law and Economics, and Coase's article became the most cited paper in all of economics.

The Man Behind the Coase Theorem

Who is this man behind this revelation? It took an unconventional education to bring forth this insightful work. Professor Ronald Coase, born in 1910 in England, suffered from a physical handicap as a youngster and thus could not attend regular school. He had to wear leg braces and was eventually enrolled in a school for “physical defectives.” But that school was managed by the same organization that ran the school for “mental defectives,” and Coase later explained that there was “some overlapping in the curriculum.”[6] As a result, Coase spent his days in basket-weaving classes, and was deprived of any formal academic instruction until age 10.

He eventually found his way to the London School of Economics, where he was a socialist until his senior year, when he enrolled in a seminar taught by Professor Arnold Plant. That course was devoted to the “invisible hand” and featured stimulating discussions without any readings. It changed Coase’s life, as he embraced the power of the free market.

Later he emigrated to the United States and eventually joined the faculty at the University of Chicago. His work almost never included a mathematical equation or formula, contrary to the modern trend in economics. To this day many in the field of law and economics, which Coase helped found, pursue quantification that he would never have done himself.

Professor Coase’s breakthrough was analogous to that of mathematician Kurt Gödel. Both deflated the arrogance of their colleagues, and as a result both received a chilly reception from their peers.

Implications of the Coase Theorem

In public policy, the Coase theorem implies that greater efficiency and prosperity can be obtained by reducing and eliminating transaction costs. Bureaucratic hurdles erected by government and the legal system increase transaction costs and reduce efficiency and prosperity. Society as a whole would be better off if transaction costs were minimized. Wealth is lost by impeding the ability of people to negotiate private contracts among themselves. The role of government to increase prosperity should focus on lowering transaction costs, not raising them.

Transaction costs are particularly large in health care, where patients and physicians must waste massive amounts of time determining how much a procedure costs, whether a third party will pay for it, and obtaining payment from that third party (such as government or an insurance company). In some cases the transaction costs are even infinite, as bureaucrats try to prohibit private contracts entirely for legitimate services. Canada forbids paying privately for medical services, requiring everyone to depend on government controls.

The Coase theorem demonstrates that these transaction costs detract from overall wealth and efficient economic behavior. Legal impediments to private contracting for medical services should be removed, as such interference frustrates the ability to reach economically optimal results. The best that government can do in controlling medical costs is simply to remove the transaction costs and get out of the way so that the parties, patients and physicians can negotiate optimal arrangements.

The Coase theorem also provides economic justification for adhering to Rule of Law, and rejecting an “evolving” Constitution. As Judge Shadur observed above, as long as there is a clear Rule of Law it does not matter to prosperity where that rule assigns the rights. Often the best courts can do is embrace the Rule of Law, and then get out of the way. Changing rules midstream, as in arbitrarily taking one’s property, is economically harmful.

There are mind-bending implications of the Coase theorem. Money itself is a property right, and that property will also be allocated to its most efficient uses regardless of who controls it, assuming rational behavior and no transaction costs. Judge Shadur explained above that the Coase theorem means “the ultimate economic result is the same no matter which way the law has resolved the issue,” and likewise the economic result is the same no matter which rational person has the property right to the wealth. Bill Gates may control $100 billion or so, but the best use of that money is dictated by demand in the free market. If Gates decides to spend the money in a way contrary to its most efficient uses in the free market, then he is wasting his own money and it is his loss.

The Coase theorem even justifies the famous observation by Jesus that we “will always have the poor among” us. Attempts by government to reduce the gap between the rich and the poor result in more transaction costs, which prevent future success. These transaction costs include higher taxes and greater regulation. The more transaction costs are injected into the system, the more inefficient it becomes, and society is worse off overall. The only way government can eliminate the poor (relative to the rich) is by imposing transaction costs that make everyone poorer. Redistributing wealth is like using a leaky bucket to transfer water from one place to another.

Assignment

Read and, if necessary, reread the above lecture. Then answer the following six questions:

1. Suppose the cross elasticity of demand for goods A and B is +3.8, and for goods X and Y is -2.7. What can you conclude about the relationship of the goods A and B, and of X and Y (i.e., are they substitutes or complements)?

2. Suppose it costs you $500 to make each of your first 5 units, then $200 to make each of your next 5 units, and then $100 to make each of your next 5 units. Costs do not decrease further for you. What is the marginal cost for you to make another unit, after you have made 15 units? What is your overall average cost per unit after you make your 16th unit? Compare the two and comment on how whether they are equal, and why.

3. Suppose your annual income increases from $20,000 to $25,000. Suppose your demand for steak increases by 10% and your demand for fast food hamburgers decreases by 5%. Which type of goods are steak, and which type are hamburgers?

4. What does an owner do when his marginal revenue exceeds his marginal cost? Explain, including what will eventually happen to the marginal revenue compared with the marginal cost for the owner.

5. What does the Coase theorem say about the desirability, and the effect, of government regulations that increase transaction costs?

6. Take the online 10-question quiz at www.conservaget.com . This quiz covers the basic concepts learned in our entire course so far. If you have a smart phone such as an iPhone or Android, this quiz should work on that too. Your score is recorded electronically but also include the score as your answer to this question (e.g., 8 out of 10).

Honors

7. Write a brief (100 words is fine) essay about an implication or consequence of the Coase theorem.

References

  1. Spencer, Contemporary Economics, at p. D-53.
  2. There is also an elasticity of supply of a particular good that we'll mention below.
  3. 3.0 3.1 3.2 http://www.boston.com/globe/search/stories/nobel/1991/1991i.html
  4. Coltman v. Commissioner, 980 F.2d 1134, 1137 (7th Cir. 1992).
  5. Warsh D., Knowledge and the Wealth of Nations: A Story of Economic Discovery 299 (2006).
  6. http://www.reason.com/news/printer/30115.html